Accounting Discretion and Purchase Price Allocation after Acquisitions
Accounting
Discretion and
Purchase
Price Allocation after Acquisitions[1]
Ivy Zhang
Carlson
School of Management
University
of Minnesota
Minneapolis,
MN 55455 izhang@csom.umn.edu
Yong Zhang
School of
Business and Management
Hong Kong University of Science and Technology
Clear Water
Bay, Hong Kong acyz@ust.hk
First
draft: August, 2006
This draft:
May, 2007
Abstract
This study investigates acquirers’ allocation of purchase
price between goodwill and identifiable intangible assets upon the completion
of acquisitions. SFAS 142 replaces goodwill amortization with periodic
impairment tests based on fair value estimates, while most identifiable
intangible assets are still amortized over finite useful lives. As a result of the
new differential accounting treatment, we predict and find that managers
allocate more purchase price to goodwill post SFAS 142 to reduce amortization
expenses when they anticipate greater discretion in future goodwill assessment
to avoid reporting impairment. We also find that older CEOs who likely care
more about short-term accounting earnings and bonus record more goodwill to
avoid amortization expenses. The results are robust to controls for the
economic determinants of the allocation. The explanatory power of acquirer/CEO
characteristics that capture managers’ reporting incentives is greater than
that of the economic determinants. In contrast, these variables cannot explain
the purchase price allocation prior to SFAS 142. The findings suggest that unverifiable
accounting measures likely deviate from the underlying economics as a result of
management exploiting their accounting discretion. We also explore the role of
external appraisers in the post SFAS 142 period and find mixed results.
1.
Introduction
Researchers and regulators have long
debated the accounting for intangible assets. The debate centers on the
relevance and reliability of intangible valuation and the existing research
produces mixed results. Value-relevance studies examine the association between
constructed or recognized value of intangibles and firms’ market values to
infer the relevance of capitalized intangibles (e.g., Lev and Sougiannis, 1996;
and Kallapur and Kwan, 2004). While these studies find significant
associations, Kallapur and Kwan (2004) also note that the association varies
with contracting considerations, suggesting that the reliability of intangible
valuation is affected by managers’ reporting incentives. A second line of
research investigates the determinants of voluntary recognition of intangible
assets to infer the reliability of intangible measurements. While Muller
(1999) finds that contracting motives significantly affect
the decision to recognize intangible assets, Wyatt (2005) argues that the
underlying economics are more important determinants of the decision than
contracting motives.
The passage of SFAS 142, Goodwill and Other Intangible Assets,
further intensifies the debate. Under SFAS 142, acquired goodwill is no longer
subject to amortization. Firms are required to allocate goodwill to reporting
units based on benefits expected from the acquisitions and then conduct
periodic goodwill impairment tests based on estimated fair values of reporting
units and identifiable net assets.[2]
Watts (2003) argues that the
implementation of SFAS 142 relies on unverifiable fair value estimates that are
likely to be manipulated. He also points out that lobbying activities played a
role in the formulation of SFAS 142. Ramanna (2006) examines the lobbying
process and argues that the lobbying firms supported the fair-value-based
goodwill impairment test as a means to seek greater flexibility in accounting.
Beatty and Weber (2006) investigate firms’ actions upon the adoption of SFAS
142 and find that opportunistic reporting incentives affected the decision to
record goodwill impairment in the transition period. It is yet to be explored
how reliable firms’ valuation of goodwill and other intangible assets is in the
routine implementation of SFAS 142.
Motivated by the debate on the accounting
for intangible assets and that on SFAS 142, this study investigates the
allocation of purchase price between goodwill and other intangible assets, the
initial valuation of these acquired assets, upon the completion of a merger or
an acquisition. While the fair value of the acquired entity is verifiable at
this point, the fair values of individual assets are not. Further, the allocation
of purchase price among different assets post SFAS 142 directly affects
acquirers’ subsequent financial reporting, as a result of the new differential
treatment of goodwill and identifiable intangible assets with finite lives. In
contrast to goodwill that is no longer amortized under SFAS 142, identifiable
intangible assets with finite lives such as developed technologies and customer
base are still subject to amortization. Recording amortization regularly
constrains managers’ accounting discretion. Also, managers are reportedly
concerned with the amortization of acquired intangibles leading to higher
reported expenses and lower earnings after acquisitions (Johnson, 1993). As
executive compensation is usually tied to earnings, intangible amortization can
reduce CEO bonuses. CEOs are thus motivated to record less intangibles post
SFAS 142 to cut amortization expenses. In particular, older CEOs likely have a
stronger incentive to avoid amortization expenses and maximize short-term
compensation, given their limited horizon and weakened career concerns. We
hypothesize that older CEOs allocate more purchase price to goodwill relative
to identifiable intangibles than determined by the underlying economics.
However, it can be costly to manipulate
the initial valuation of acquired intangible assets by recording more goodwill
relative to other intangible assets. Allocating more purchase price
to goodwill increases the likelihood of large goodwill impairment write-offs in
the future. Pender (2001) argues that goodwill write-offs are considered a
manifestation of past acquisition mistakes that can lead to management
dismissal. As a result, we predict that managers likely manipulate
the allocation towards goodwill when expecting that they can hide future
goodwill impairment by exercising discretion in the tests.[3]
We measure managers’ capability to avoid future goodwill writeoffs with
the three acquirer characteristics identified by Ramanna (2006): a high
market-to-book ratio, large amount of unverifiable assets, and multiple
reporting units.
First, we test our predictions on
acquisitions post SFAS 142. As predicted, we find that older CEOs tend to
allocate more purchase price to goodwill. Also, an acquirer with more
discretion in future goodwill assessment, namely, with a higher market-to-book
ratio and less verifiable assets, records more goodwill relative to other
intangible assets. While acquirer/CEO characteristics can be correlated with
the goodwill-intangible allocation to the extent that they capture acquirers’
preference for certain targets and synergies from the combination, our findings
are robust to controlling for target characteristics, such as target
market-to-book ratio, R&D, and advertising expenditures, and measures of
acquisition synergies. We also find that acquirers with multiple segments allocate
more purchase price to goodwill relative to intangible assets, but the
significance of the result is sensitive to the inclusion of proxies for the
underlying economics. Target book-to-market ratio and R&D expenditures,
capturing target’s economic rents and unrecognized developed technologies, are
negatively correlated with the goodwill-intangible ratio.
Our model explains about 32% of the
variation of the goodwill-intangible ratio with proxies for the underlying
economics and management expected discretion in future goodwill assessment. The
acquirer characteristics capturing management expected discretion alone explain
23% of the variation of the goodwill-intangible allocation and their
incremental explanatory power is greater than the economic variables. The
results suggest that managers’ accounting preferences have a substantial impact
on reporting reliability when accounting measures are unverifiable. To
illustrate the role that verifiability plays in the allocation process, we also
use the same set of variables to explain the allocation of purchase price to
tangible assets, the valuation of which presumably involves less discretion.[4]
None of the acquirer characteristic variables significantly explains the
tangible to total purchase price ratio.
Second, we examine the purchase price
allocation of acquisitions prior to SFAS 142 to further mitigate the concern
that our variables capturing management’s expected discretion in future
goodwill tests are related to the economics underlying the allocation. Since
our predictions on the variables of interest are based on the new accounting
methods prescribed by SFAS 142, we do not expect them to explain the pre-SFAS
142 allocation. Also, in the regression to explain the allocation decision, we
expect the coefficients on these variables to differ significantly between the
pre and post SFAS 142 regimes. Our findings are largely consistent with these
expectations, suggesting that our post SFAS 142 results cannot be solely
explained by the economics of goodwill/intangible valuation, but rather related
to the implementation of SFAS 142.
Furthermore, we investigate mechanisms
that potentially enhance the reliability of the valuation of intangible assets.
Dietrich et al. (2001) and Muller and Riedl (2002) find that valuation of
investment properties conducted by external independent appraisers is more
accurate and associated with less information asymmetry than internal
valuation. We explore the role of external appraisers in the allocation of
acquisition price, an accounting procedure presumably less verifiable than the
valuation of tangible properties. We find that most of the variables capturing
management’s opportunism are not significantly associated with the allocation
between goodwill and other intangibles in the presence of an external
appraiser; only CEO tenure, which also proxies for CEO entrenchment, still
affects the allocation. The findings suggest that external appraisers can
constrain management’ opportunism in intangible valuation to a certain extent
but unlikely eliminate it.
Finally, for a sub-sample of multi-segment
acquirers, we conduct an additional test examining the correlation between the
profitability of a reporting unit and the percentage of goodwill allocated to
the unit. If managers prefer greater flexibility in future goodwill assessments
and/or impairment decisions, more profitable reporting units are likely to
receive more goodwill allocation. Consistent with the prediction, we find a
strong positive correlation between the profitability ranking of a reporting
unit and the percentage of goodwill allocated to that unit. While we cannot
completely rule out that firms expand their profitable product lines through
acquisitions, the results are robust to controlling for industry commonality
between the target and different reporting units of the acquiring company.
This paper contributes to the literature
in several ways. First, this study sheds light on the reliability of intangible
valuation by investigating managers’ valuation of goodwill and other intangible
assets right after acquisitions. We show that managers likely manipulate the
allocation between goodwill and other intangibles when the benefit (cost) of
manipulation is higher (lower).
Moreover, we find that management’s opportunism is more important than
the economic determinants in explaining the allocation decision, casting doubt
on the reliability of intangible and goodwill valuation under SFAS 142. The
evidence suggests that the impact of managerial discretion cannot be ignored in
interpreting the reported accounting information post SFAS 142.
Second, more generally, our findings have
implications for fair-value-based accounting procedures that are built on
unverifiable estimates. SFAS 142 is considered an important step towards
fair-value-based accounting (Watts, 2003). Our results indicate that the
unverifiable fair value estimates can deviate from the underlying economics as
a result of management taking advantage of the discretion in measurement. While
this study does not explore the net benefits or costs of fair-value-based
accounting relative to alternative accounting methods and therefore cannot
generate direct implications for standard setting, the findings are useful as
inputs in evaluating fairvalue-based accounting procedures.
Third, our results also suggest that
external appraisers potentially play an important role in enhancing the
reliability of fair value measurements. The findings can help users of
financial statements better assess fair value measurements and can also be useful
to regulators in assessing fair-value-based accounting procedures and
disclosures.
Finally, this study answers the call by
Healy and Whalen (1999) for more research on how earnings are managed. Our
findings reveal a manipulable accounting procedure that has been largely
overlooked in the prior literature and have implications for research on the
impairment of acquired assets.
The rest of the paper is organized as
follows. Section 2 reviews related provisions in SFAS 142 and previous studies.
Development of the hypotheses is explained in Section 3. Section 4 discusses
sample selection procedures and empirical results. Section 5 concludes.
2. Background
2.1. Accounting for acquired goodwill and
identifiable intangible assets
Acquired goodwill and identifiable
intangible assets were both recognized and amortized over their estimated
useful lives until SFAS 142 became effective in July 2001. SFAS 142 promulgates
new approaches to allocate acquired goodwill within the acquirer upon
completion of an acquisition and new accounting procedures for assessing
goodwill subsequent to the acquisition. The first new procedure is related to the
allocation of acquisition price. Acquirers need to allocate the purchase price
to acquired tangible and identifiable intangible assets, such as patents and
developed technologies, based on their fair values with the remainder recorded
as goodwill. Next is the allocation of goodwill. Prior to SFAS 142, SFAS 121, Accounting for the Impairment of Longlived
Assets and for Long-lived Assets to Be Disposed of, required firms to
allocate goodwill to acquired tangible assets or asset groups ratably based on
the relative fair values of these assets. In contrast, SFAS 142 requires
acquirers to allocate goodwill to reporting units based on the expected
benefits each reporting unit obtains from the acquisition. The estimation of
expected benefits, or synergies, involves assessing the fair values of
reporting units before and after the acquisition.
Second, SFAS 142 replaces goodwill
amortization with periodic impairment tests based on fair value estimates. In
conducting the impairment tests, firms first compare the book value and
estimated fair value of each reporting unit to identify potential impairment.
If the book value of a reporting unit exceeds its fair value, firms should then
estimate the fair value of identifiable assets and liabilities and compare it
to the unit’s fair value. The implied fair value of goodwill is thus the excess
of the fair value of the reporting unit over the amounts assigned to its assets
and liabilities. If the book value of goodwill exceeds its implied fair value,
goodwill impairment should be recognized.
SFAS 142 promulgates different
rules for identifiable intangible assets with finite or indefinite lives. Similar
to acquired goodwill, an identifiable intangible asset with an indefinite life,
such as a trademark, is not amortized. It is assessed for impairment by a
comparison of its estimated fair value and the carrying book value. The vast
majority of acquired identifiable intangible assets, however, are considered
having finite lives (see SFAS 142 Appendix A for examples of intangible assets
with an indefinite life and also Section 4 for discussions of descriptive
statistics). An acquired intangible asset with a finite life is amortized over
its useful life under SFAS 142. An impairment loss should be recognized if the
book value of an intangible asset exceeds the undiscounted cash flows that
asset is expected to generate.[5]
2.2. Related research
The accounting for goodwill and
intangibles has been debated for decades. The debate relates to specific
accounting treatments of intangibles but fundamentally centers on the relevance
and reliability of intangibles valuation. One line of research focuses on the
value relevance of capitalized
intangibles by examining the association between constructed
or recognized value of intangibles and firms’ market values. For example, Lev
and Sougiannis (1996) treat R&D expenses as if they were capitalized and
examine the relation between the constructed R&D value and firms’ market
values. Barth et al. (1998) examine the relation between brand name values
estimated by the financial press and firms’ market values. Kallapur and Kwan
(2004) investigate the association between recognized brand names and firms’
market values for a sample of U.K. listed firms. While these studies find the
association to be significant and positive, some of them also note problems
with the reliability of intangible measurements. Kallapur and Kwan (2004) find
that the association is lower when firms have stronger contracting incentives
related to listing requirements and debt financing. Furthermore, the approach
of inferring value relevance from the documented associations has been
challenged (see
Holthausen and Watts, 2001).
Another line of research investigates the
determinants of a firm’s decision in recognizing intangible assets to infer the
relevance and reliability of the accounting for intangibles. Muller (1999)
finds that contracting incentives such as exchange listing requirements and
debt contracting have a significant impact on the decision to capitalize
acquired brand names in the U.K. However, Wyatt (2005) argues that the
underlying economics such as prevailing technology conditions are more
important determinants of the recognition of intangibles than contracting
incentives. She examines the intangible recognition decision for a large cross
section of Australian listed firms and constructs the technology conditions
variables largely at the industry level. However, while her technology
condition variables can explain a significant portion of the variation of
recognized identifiable intangibles, they do not explain much of the variation
in goodwill and capitalized R&D assets.
The passage of the fair-value-based SFAS
142 extended the debate on the accounting for goodwill and other intangibles.
Watts (2003) argues that the implementation of SFAS 142 relies on unverifiable
fair value estimates that are likely to be manipulated. He also contends that
lobbying activities played a role in the formulation of SFAS 142. Ramanna
(2006) investigates firms’ lobbying positions in the rulemaking period of SFAS
142 and finds that those anticipating greater accounting flexibility in the
goodwill impairment assessment were more likely to support the impairment test
proposal. He suggests that firms are likely to use the manipulation potential
post SFAS 142. Beatty and Weber (2006) examine the determinants of firms’
accounting choices in the initial impairment assessment under SFAS 142. They
find that equity market concerns and contracting incentives affected firms’
decision to accelerate or delay the impairment recognition. Such findings are
consistent with the notion that management incentives affect fair value
estimates of goodwill. However, since their study examines an extraordinary
one-time charge, the findings may not be generalizable to routine reporting of
fair value estimates. Bens and Heltzer (2006) investigate the timeliness and
information content of goodwill write-offs around SFAS 142 passage and they do
not find any significant changes post SFAS 142. Li et al. (2006) find that
investors and financial analysts react negatively to the announcement of an
impairment loss in the transition period of SFAS 142 and that the impairment
loss is followed by a decline in subsequent performance.
This study extends the research on SFAS
142 as well as that on the reliability of the accounting for intangibles. We
present detailed information about the initial fair value assessment of
acquired assets, the allocation of purchase price upon the completion of
acquisitions. While studies on goodwill impairment focus on poor performing
firms, we examine a more general setting since the allocation is performed by
every acquirer. Our findings further the understanding of firms’ valuation of
intangibles and their implementation of SFAS 142 absent extreme economic
performance. In addition, we examine not only whether an accounting choice is
affected by management incentives, but also the less researched question - how
important management incentives are compared to the underlying economics. While
Wyatt (2005) examines this question for firms in various industries, we investigate
a different accounting choice using a sample of firms with more homogeneous
asset structure (to be discussed in detail in Section 4), thereby providing
additional insights. 3. Hypotheses
As discussed in Section 2.1, SFAS 142
grants differential treatment for goodwill and identifiable intangible assets,
potentially motivating managers to manipulate the allocation of purchase price
between the two asset categories. Meanwhile, the allocation process involves
unverifiable estimation of fair values of parts of a firm, thereby providing
opportunities for manipulation. Whether and to what extent the allocation is
manipulated depends on the benefits and costs of such manipulation.
3.1.1.
Benefits of manipulating the allocation of purchase price
It has been widely noted in the financial
press and among practitioners that management is concerned that the
amortization of intangibles increases reported expenses and depresses earnings
(e.g., Johnson, 1993; and Moehrle and Moehrle, 2001). This concern may result
from managers’ belief that investors fixate on reported earnings. It may also
arise because managers’ bonuses are tied to reported earnings (Healy, 1985).
Prior to SFAS 142, acquirers could avoid amortization of acquired intangibles
by using the pooling of interest method to account for acquisitions. Lys and
Vincent (1995) indicate that acquirers may incur significant additional costs
to obtain the more ‘favorable’ pooling of interest accounting treatment for
acquisitions. SFAS 142 bans the pooling of interest accounting and it is
alleged that the elimination of goodwill amortization in SFAS 142 is a
compromise regulators offer for the restriction (Moehrle and Moehrle, 2001; and
Ramanna, 2006). Under SFAS 142, in all circumstances, acquired identifiable intangible
assets with finite lives are amortized while goodwill is not.
If managers are concerned with intangible
amortization depressing earnings and thereby reducing their bonuses, they will
allocate more purchase price to goodwill in order to avoid future amortization
expenses. In particular, older CEOs likely have stronger incentives to boost up
shortterm earnings, given their limited horizon and weakened career concerns.
Prior research argues that CEOs close to the end of their tenure focus more on
short-term earnings to maximize their compensation rather than long-term
performance. For example, Dechow and Sloan (1991) find that CEOs reduce R&D
expenditures to increase reported earnings during the final years in office.
CEO career concerns potentially constrain managers’ opportunism (Brickley et
al., 1999). However, as CEOs age, career concerns become weaker. Older CEOs
likely lose less if the misallocation of purchase price is discovered or the
misallocation leads to goodwill impairment in the future. Thus, the net
benefits of manipulating the allocation between goodwill and other intangibles
are greater for older CEOs. We predict,
H1: Ceteris paribus,
post SFAS 142, older CEOs allocate more purchase price to goodwill relative to
identifiable intangible assets than expected.
The benefits of reducing intangible
amortization expenses can also vary across firms with firm characteristics.
Burgstahler and Dichev (1997) find that firms manage earnings to avoid
reporting losses. As a result, acquirers reporting small positive earnings
before an acquisition are likely more concerned with amortization depressing
earnings. Also, intangible amortization reduces net assets on a regular basis.
Recording less identifiable intangibles and reducing amortization expenses can
help acquirers maintain a higher net worth. Acquirers with debt covenants based
on net worth likely have greater incentives to reduce amortization. However,
the descriptive statistics in Section 4.3 show that very few acquirers in our
sample report small positive earnings before the acquisitions or have debt
covenants based on net worth. Thus, there is no substantial variation in the
benefits of avoiding amortization charges in our sample. Our main tests
therefore assume constant benefits of manipulating the purchase price
allocation towards goodwill and additional analyses of potential variation are
discussed in Section 4.5.
3.1.2.
Costs of manipulating the allocation of purchase price
Goodwill impairment write-offs
Manipulating the allocation of purchase
price can impose costs on acquirers. Allocating more purchase price to goodwill
increases the likelihood of large goodwill impairment write-offs in the future.
Such write-offs are likely costly to managers and firms. Pender (2001) argues
that goodwill write-offs are considered a manifestation of past acquisition
mistakes that can lead to management dismissals.[6]
Li et al. (2006) find that investors and analysts revise their expectations of
a firm downward upon the announcement of a goodwill impairment loss.
Consequently, acquirers anticipating a lower likelihood of future goodwill
impairment are more likely to manipulate the allocation of purchase price
towards goodwill.
We recognize that under certain
circumstances, such as corporate restructuring or management turnovers,
managers can include goodwill write-offs as a part of earnings baths. The
possibility of hiding goodwill impairment in earnings baths may make goodwill
write-offs appear less costly to managers than otherwise. However, anecdotal evidence
(e.g., the AOL Time Warner goodwill write-off in 2002) suggests that when
impairment occurs, managers are not always able to avoid losses in human
capital by taking a ‘bath’.
The likelihood of writing off goodwill is
determined by the likelihood of incurring economic losses and managers’ ability
to hide the losses through managing the impairment assessment of goodwill. Li
et al. (2006) examine the relation between the indicators of overpayment at the
time of acquisition and the likelihood of reporting a goodwill impairment loss.
While they find several indicator variables are significantly correlated with
reporting impairment, the overall explanatory power of the model (2-4%)
suggests that the impairment is not well anticipated at the time of acquisition.
As a result, in the main analyses, we assume that the likelihood of economic
impairment of acquired goodwill is constant for all acquisitions. In Section
4.5, we conduct additional analyses, relaxing the assumption that economic
impairment is equally likely. In our main analyses, we focus on how
management’s ability to manipulate future impairment assessment and hide
potential losses affects the initial valuation of intangible assets. We predict
that managers allocate more purchase price to goodwill when they expect greater
flexibility in future goodwill impairment assessment to avoid reporting losses.[7]
Ramanna (2006) identifies three firm
characteristics associated with greater manipulation potential in the SFAS 142
goodwill impairment assessment. First, he argues that firms with higher
reporting-unit market-to-book ratios obtain greater flexibility under SFAS
142. Firms with higher reporting-unit
market-to-book ratios likely have more internally generated economic rents. In
the impairment test of acquired goodwill, the book value of acquired goodwill
is compared to the fair value of goodwill at the reporting unit level, which
includes the value of internally generated rents. Thus, when purchased goodwill
is impaired, management is better able to cover the losses using internally
generated rents and delay reporting an impairment loss for reporting units with
high market-to-book ratios. We expect firms with higher reporting-unit
market-to-book ratios to allocate more acquisition price to goodwill relative
to identifiable intangible assets.
For a firm with a single reporting unit,
the reporting unit’s market-to-book ratio equals that of the firm. For firms
with multiple reporting units, reporting-unit-level market-to-book ratios are
unobservable. Since a higher average reporting-unit market-to-book ratio leads
to a higher firm-level market-to-book ratio, we use the firm-level
market-to-book ratio as a proxy for reporting-unit internally generated rents.
We hypothesize,
H2: Ceteris Paribus, post
SFAS 142, an acquirer with a higher market-to-book ratio prior to the
acquisition allocates more purchase price to goodwill relative to identifiable
intangible assets than expected.
Second, since the fair value of
goodwill in a reporting unit is estimated as the excess of the fair value of
the reporting unit over the fair value of its identifiable net assets, Ramanna
(2006) argues that the less verifiable the net assets are, the greater
discretion firms have in determining the existence and amount of impairment
losses. Thus, we expect firms with less verifiable assets to allocate more
purchase price to goodwill.
H3: Ceteris Paribus, post
SFAS 142, an acquirer with less verifiable assets allocates more purchase price
to goodwill relative to identifiable intangible assets than expected.
Third, as Watts (2003) points out,
synergies from an acquisition are likely joint benefits that cannot be
allocated across reporting units in a meaningful manner. Ramanna (2006) thus
expects the existence of several large units to allow managers greater
accounting flexibility in the sense that they can allocate goodwill across
units strategically. However, it seems unnecessary to require multiple large units in order for a firm to gain
greater discretion in the goodwill allocation. Consider two firms with the same
size: one firm has only one reporting unit while the other has two. Managers of
the two-reporting-unit firm have the option to allocate goodwill and evaluate
for goodwill impairment in the same way as the first firm, namely, allocate
goodwill to the two units based on their fair values and then use a firm-level
average earnings multiple to estimate reporting unit fair values in subsequent
impairment tests. In addition, the two-reporting-unit firm has the option to
strategically allocate more goodwill to the more profitable reporting unit and
manage the fair value estimates for that unit in subsequent tests.
Moreover, even if a multiple-reporting-unit firm does not
allocate goodwill to multiple units,
it will still have greater flexibility in future
determinations of reporting unit fair values, and consequently, goodwill fair
values than a single-reporting-unit firm. The allocation of expected future
cash flows across reporting units again involves allocation of joint benefits
and costs. Since the fair value of each unit is unverifiable, managers of a
multiple-unit firm have greater room to manipulate unit-level fair value
estimates than those of a single-unit firm in estimating the firm’s fair value.
Hence, we hypothesize,
H4: Ceteris Paribus,
post SFAS 142, an acquirer with
multiple reporting units allocates more purchase price to goodwill relative to
identifiable intangible assets than expected.
Other costs/constraints with manipulation of
purchase price allocation
Dietrich et al. (2001) and Muller and
Riedl (2002) argue that external appraisers may serve as monitors in fair value
measurements and enhance the credibility of accounting information. They find
that valuation of investment properties conducted by external independent
appraisers is more accurate and associated with less information asymmetry than
internal valuation. If external appraisers constrain managers’ manipulation of
the initial valuation of goodwill and other intangible assets, we expect,
H5: The association between variables capturing CEO
age/management’s discretion in future goodwill assessment and the
goodwill-intangible allocation is more pronounced when the initial valuation is
conducted internally.
In addition, manipulation of accounting
numbers is likely constrained by auditors and firms’ litigation concerns. Prior
research uses the size of an auditor to proxy for audit quality (e.g., Dietrich
et al., 2001) and industry classifications to proxy for litigation risks (e.g.,
Francis et al., 1994). The descriptive statistics reported in the subsequent
section show that most of our sample firms are audited by the Big 4 auditors
and operate in industries with high litigation risks. As a result, we do not
focus on these constraints of manipulation and discuss their impact in Section
4.5.
4. Sample Selection and Empirical Analysis
4.1. Purchase price allocation post SFAS 142
4.1.1.
Data
Companies have been required to disclose the
allocation of purchase price since SFAS 142 became effective in July 2001. We
begin our sample selection with all the acquisitions completed between July
2001 and October 2005 as reported by Thompson Financial’s Securities Data
Company
(SDC) database. We further require that both the acquiring
company and the target company be publicly traded before the acquisition and
that the target’s primary SIC industry be business services (2-digit SIC code
73). SDC reports 137 deals meeting these requirements.
We focus on the business services industry
for several reasons. First, different industries have different industry
specific intangible assets, the amount of which is hard to model in the
crossindustry setting. [8]
By focusing on a single industry, we mitigate the heterogeneity in intangible
assets structure and thereby better capture the economic determinants of the
allocation decision. As purchase price allocations are likely to be affected by
the underlying economics of the target companies, having a relatively
homogeneous sample reduces the possibility that our results are driven by
alternative explanations such as different operating environments among
different industries. Second, M&A activities are very active in the
business services industry. In our sample period, acquisitions with the target
being a business service firm account for almost 30% of all acquisitions with
the target being public. Thus, our sample represents a significant proportion
of all acquisitions. Third, companies operating in this industry are likely to
generate a significant amount of intangible assets, which makes their
accounting decisions about intangibles especially important.
For each deal, we collected the
information about purchase price allocation and whether an external appraiser
was involved from the acquirer’s 10-K filing to the US Securities and Exchange
Commission (SEC).8 Information required to construct measures of
acquisition cost allocation is available for 112 deals. Requiring the
acquirers’ financial information from COMPUSTAT reduced the sample size to 103
deals by 81 unique acquiring companies. Requiring the same for the targets
further reduced the sample size to 98 deals by 78 unique acquiring companies.
We also obtained other acquisition deal characteristics from the SDC and
segment level financial information from
COMPUSTAT. CEO data is from Execucomp and supplemented by
information collected from firms’ proxy statements and 10-K reports. In
addition, we obtained stock return information from CRSP and acquirer debt
covenant data from Dealscan. Table 1 summarizes the sample filter information.
4.1.2.
Variable Measurement and Research Design
We test our hypotheses empirically through
the use of the following variables:
TANGIBLE
|
= the net amount allocated to tangible assets and liabilities as a
percentage of the total purchase price of the deal,
|
GOODWILL
|
= the amount allocated to goodwill or identifiable intangible assets
with an indefinite life as a percentage of the combined amount allocated to
all intangible assets, including both goodwill and other intangible assets
(also known as identifiable intangible assets),
|
ACEO_AGE
|
= age of the CEO of the acquirer at the time of the
acquisition,
|
ACEO_TENURE = the number of years the CEO
of the acquirer has been in office,
A_BTM
|
= the acquirer’s book value of common equity divided by its market
value of common equity,
|
A_VERIF
|
= the acquirer’s verifiable net assets (Cash +
Investment – Debt – Preferred
Equity)
divided by its total net assets (Assets – Liabilities),
|
A_SEG
|
= a dummy variable equaling one if the acquirer has more than one
reporting segment, and zero otherwise
|
A_SIZE
|
= Ln(market value of equity of the acquirer),
|
A_SP
|
= a dummy variable equaling one for acquirers reporting small positive
earnings prior to the acquisition (0 < = earnings/total assets < =
0.01), and zero otherwise,
|
A_NW
|
= a dummy variable equaling one if the acquirer has a debt covenant
based on net worth, and zero otherwise,
|
A_LITI
|
= a dummy variable equaling one if the acquirer is in one of the four
high litigation risk industries identified by Francis et al. (1994):
pharmaceuticals/biotechnology
(SIC codes 2833-2836, 8731-8734), computers (3570-3577, 7370-7374),
electronics (3600-3674), and retail
(5200-5961),
and zero otherwise,
|
T_BTM
|
=
the target’s book value of common equity divided by its market value of
|
common equity,
T_SALES
|
= the target’s Ln(Sales) divided by its Ln(Assets),
|
T_ADV
|
= the target’s advertising expense divided by its sales,
|
T_RD
|
= the target’s R&D expense divided by its sales,
|
WT_CAR
|
= the weighted-average of the acquirer’s and the target’s abnormal
stock return, computed as residuals from a market model, over a 3-day window
around the acquisition deal announcement day (abnormal returns are computed
as market-model residuals),
|
COMMON
|
= a dummy
variable used to measure the level of commonality between the
|
4-digit SIC industries in which the
target and the acquirer operate;
COMMON is assigned a value of one
if N_COMMON/N_ACQ is larger than 0.5, or zero otherwise, where N_COMMON is the
number of common industries between the target and the acquirer and N_ACQ is
the number of industries in which the acquirer operates.
Financial information about the target and
the acquirer is measured over the fiscal year prior to the year of acquisition.[9]
There are five groups of variables. The first group includes TANGIBLE and
GOODWILL, where TANGIBLE measures how purchase price is allocated between
tangible assets/liabilities and intangible assets, and GOODWILL measures how
purchase price is allocated between goodwill or trademark and other intangible
assets, conditional on the total amount of purchase price allocated to
intangible assets. We include identifiable intangible assets with an indefinite
life as a part of GOODWILL because these assets receive accounting treatment
very similar to goodwill in terms of amortization expense and future
impairment.[10]
TANGIBLE and
GOODWILL are the dependent variables of
our empirical analysis.
The second group of variables captures
characteristics of the CEO of the acquirer.
ACEO_AGE equals the age of the CEO as of the acquisition
year. ACEO_AGE is likely positively correlated with the tenure of the CEO. A
CEO with a long tenure is more likely entrenched than a CEO who has just taken
office. An entrenched CEO can increase his/her compensation directly by
influencing the compensation contract and therefore the benefits of avoiding
amortization expenses can be minimal. Meanwhile, it is unclear whether an
entrenched CEO faces lower costs of manipulating the allocation. Entrenched
CEOs may be less likely terminated after reporting goodwill impairment, but
once the impairment attracts public attention and leads to management turnover,
they have more to lose. It is thus an empirical question how CEO tenure is
related to the allocation.
We include ACEO_TENURE in subsequent
analyses because of its potential correlation with
ACEO_AGE and the allocation decision.
The third group of variables, which
includes A_BTM, A_VERIF, A_SEG, A_SIZE, A_SP, A_NW, A_LITI, and A_AUDIT,
captures acquirer characteristics. These variables are constructed using the
financial information of the acquiring companies in the fiscal years prior to
the acquisition. Hypotheses two through four predict that A_BTM, A_VERIF, and
A_SEG shall affect the acquirers’ decision of purchase price allocation.[11]
As A_SEG can capture the size of the acquirer, we also include A_SIZE in
subsequent regressions to control for this effect. The definition of A_VERIF
follows Ramanna (2006).[12]
A_SP and A_NW are constructed to capture the benefits of manipulating the
purchase price allocation. A_LITI and A_AUDIT are proxies for litigation risks
and audit quality. However, as the descriptive statistics reported in Section
4.3 show, these four variables exhibit little variation in our sample.
We predict that acquirer characteristics
are correlated with the goodwill-intangible allocation ratio because of
cross-sectional variation in the benefits and costs of manipulation. The
association between these characteristics and the allocation can also be
explained by certain acquirers preferring certain targets. For example,
acquirers with more growth options (low A_BTM) may find a target with greater
growth potentials to be a good match and record more goodwill to reflect the
unrecognized growth options of the target. As a result, we control for target
characteristics and synergies generated from the combination.
The fourth group of variables includes
T_SALE, T_ADV, T_RD, and T_BTM. We use these target characteristics to control
for any difference in operating environment and investment opportunity sets
that may be correlated with the underlying economics that affect purchase price
allocations. The descriptive statistics (Table 3) show that trademarks,
developed technology, and customer relationships are the most important
identifiable intangible assets recorded. We thus need to control for target
characteristics that are associated with a higher likelihood of recording these
assets. First, targets with more sales revenue likely have a larger customer
base and more purchase price should be allocated to the acquired customer base.
Second, more advertising expenditures are likely associated with greater brand
name recognition, so we predict a positive correlation between T_ADV and the
purchase price allocated to trademarks. Third, if targets with more R&D
expenditures are more likely to have developed useful technologies, more purchase
price should be recorded as developed technology.
In addition, internally generated rents,
or goodwill, are reflected in the market value of a firm but not in the book
value. If a target has more internally generated goodwill and thus a high
marketto-book ratio, the acquirer is likely to recognize more goodwill from the
acquisition since both the target’s internally generated goodwill and the
synergy created by the combination are recorded. However, a target with a high
market-to-book ratio can also have more unrecognized intangibles that can be
recorded after the acquisition. Therefore, we predict a negative correlation
between TANGIBLE and T_BTM, but do not have a prediction for the relation
between GOODWILL and
T_BTM.
The last group of variables, WT_CAR and
COMMON, proxies for the amount of synergy potentially arising from the
acquisitions and therefore affecting the decisions of purchase price
allocation. WT_CAR measures the market’s estimate of the change of the combined
value of the target and the acquirer at the initial announcement of the
acquisition.[13]
COMMON measures the extent of overlapping between the industries in which both
the target and the acquirer operate. While goodwill recorded after an
acquisition includes at least part of the synergies generated by the
acquisition, it is unclear how the goodwill-intangible ratio would vary with
synergies. For example, acquisitions with the acquirer and the target in the
same industry may generate greater synergies, but part of the synergies can be recorded
as identifiable intangible assets, such as customer base.
Therefore, we make no predictions for the
relation between WT_CAR/COMMON and GOODWILL.
We use the following multivariate
regression to test the hypotheses:
GOODWILLi
= α0 + α1 ACEO_AGEi + a2 ACEO_TENUREi
+ a3 A_BTMi + α4 A_VERIFi + α5
A_SEGi
+ a6 A_SIZEi+ α7T_BTMi + α8T_SALESi
+ α9T_ADVi + α10 T_RDi + α11 WT_CARi
+ α12
COMMONi + εi (1)
As described in Section 3 of the paper,
H1, H2, H3, and H4 predict that α1
> 0, α3 < 0, α4 < 0, and a5
> 0, respectively. We also predict that a8<0, a9<0, and a10<0.
As there is little variation in A_SP, A_NW, A_LITI, and A_AUDIT, we cannot
conduct a powerful test of how the allocation varies with the benefits of
manipulation or the litigation risks. We discuss regression results including
these three variables in sensitivity analyses.
Our hypotheses about purchase price
allocation are based on the trade-offs between goodwill, which is
non-amortizable under SFAS 141 and SFAS 142, and identifiable intangible
assets, which are subject to amortization. Therefore, our predictions should be
unique to the allocation of purchase price among different types of intangible
assets; we do not have the same trade-offs and therefore the same predictions
with respect to the general allocation of purchase price between tangible
assets and intangible assets. One may argue that managers, when expecting
greater flexibility in future goodwill impairment tests, may have similar
incentives to lower the valuation of tangibles assets in order to increase the
amount of purchase price assigned to goodwill. We have two reasons to believe
that managers’ discretion in tangible assets valuation is a less important
issue in our setting. First, tangible assets likely constitute a lesser part of
total assets for firms operating in the business service industry that we focus
on, which implies any discretion exercised in tangible asset valuation has a
lesser economic consequence. Second, the valuation of tangible assets likely
involves less uncertainty and therefore any discretion exercised is more likely
to be corrected by monitoring parties such as auditors and boards of directors.
Therefore, we run the following regression as a benchmark regression with the
same independent variables but with the allocation between tangible and
intangible assets as the dependent variable.
TANGIBLEi
= α0 + α1 ACEO_AGEi
+ a2 ACEO_TENUREi
+ a3 A_BTMi + α4 A_VERIFi + α5
A_SEGi
+ a6 A_SIZEi+ α7T_BTMi + α8T_SALESi
+ α9T_ADVi + α10 T_RDi + α11 WT_CARi
+ α12
COMMONi + εi (2)
4.1.3.
Descriptive Statistics
Table 2 reports the distribution of our
sample across industries and over time. By construction, all target firms’
primary industries are the Business Services industry (2-digit SIC code
73). Among them, the vast majority (87 out 103) operates
primarily in Computer Programming, Data Processing, and Other Computer Related
Services (3-digit SIC code 737). The strong industry clustering of the target
firms in our sample suggests that we have a relatively homogeneous sample.
Likewise, the acquirers are also highly clustered in similar industries: of the
103 deals, 79 have acquiring firms with 73 as the 2-digit primary industry SIC
code, while 76 of them have 737 as the 3digit primary industry SIC code. Our
sample period (July 2001 to October 2005) spans over five different calendar
years; the sample shows no obvious clustering in time.
Panel A of Table 3 reports the descriptive
statistics. SFAS 141 requires that, in a business combination, the acquirer
include in the purchase price all costs associated with acquiring the target
company’s net assets or stock, including the value of the consideration given
to the owners of the acquired company as well as other direct costs such as
finders’ fees and accounting, legal, and appraisal fees. The average purchase
price is about $480 million and the median is about $119 million. Consistent
with the existing literature (e.g. Andrade et al., 2001), the target companies
enjoyed a significant 31% increase in stock prices at the initial announcement
of the acquisition. In contrast, the acquiring companies in our sample suffered
a significantly negative 2% stock return. The change in the combined value of
both the acquirer and the target is a negligible 0.4% and is not significantly
different from zero. The dummy variable COMMON has a value of one for 28% for
the sample.
For the acquirers, the average market
value is about $7,555 million and the median is about $887 million. The average
acquirer book-to-market ratio is about 0.46. An average acquirer’s verifiable
asset constitutes 57% of its total net assets. The average number of operating
segments for the acquirers is 2.31, but the median is one, indicating that more
than half of the acquirers have only one operating segment. Only three
observations of our sample have small positive earnings or net worth covenant.
Eighty percent of the acquirers operate primarily in a high litigation risk
industry. We also examine both the primary industry and the secondary
industries of the acquirer-target combination and find that 90% of the combination
operates at least in one of the high litigation risk industries. The vast
majority of acquirers (93%) are audited by big auditors.
For the target companies, the average
book-to-market ratio is 0.53 and the average sales revenue is $163 million. In
the year prior to being acquired, an average target company spends only 1% of
its sales revenue on advertising but spends 29% of its sales revenue on R&D
activities.
SFAS 141 requires that the acquiring
companies allocate the purchase price to individual assets, tangible as well as
intangible, and liabilities based on fair value. In our sample, on average, net
tangible assets account for only 8% of the purchase price, but the variation is
large, with the 25 percentile and the 75 percentile at -3% and 27%,
respectively. The net value allocated to tangibles can be negative when the
fair value of tangible liabilities exceeds the fair value of tangible assets.
Among the intangibles, goodwill accounts for 72%, on average. Similarly there
is also a fair amount of variation in the portion of intangibles classified as
goodwill, with the 25 percentile and the 75 percentile at 65% and 86%,
respectively.
Panel B reports statistics on categories
of identifiable intangible assets reported by acquirers in our sample. There
are roughly six categories of identifiable intangible assets in our sample:
trademark, developed technology, customer base and customer loyalty, patents,
non-competing agreements and contracts, and other agreements and contracts.
Among them, developed technology and customer base and customer loyalty are
reported most often and account for most of the dollar value. The life of these
intangibles, upon which calculation of amortization expenses will be based,
varies greatly across different intangible categories and also has a wide range
in each individual category. This is consistent with the arguments about the
inherent difficulty in assessing the value of intangible assets.
4.1.4.
Correlations
Table 4 reports the pair-wise correlations
among different variables in our sample.
GOODWILL is significantly correlated with three acquirer
characteristics ACEO_AGE, A_BTM and A_AVERIF in the directions predicted by H1
– H3. Although the correlation between GOODWILL and A_SEG is positive,
consistent with the prediction of H3, the two-tailed probability is only 17%.
GOODWILL and ACEO_AGE are also positively correlated. In contrast, none of the
acquirer characteristics is significantly correlated with TANGIBLE, which
suggests that, unlike the valuation of intangible assets, tangible asset
valuation is subject to less discretion resulting from acquirer incentives.
As for target characteristics, T_BTM is
negatively correlated with GOODWILL. Smith and Watts (1992) argue that a
company’s book-to-market ratio is inversely related to its investment
opportunity set. The negative correlation between T_BTM and GOODWILL suggests
the value of the target companies’ investment sets are more likely linked to
unidentifiable intangible assets than to identifiable intangible assets. T_RD
is also negatively correlated with GOODWILL. Companies that spend more on
R&D are more likely to have developed mature technologies and therefore
recognize more identifiable intangible assets such as technology or patents,
increasing the amount of identifiable intangible assets and correspondingly
decreasing the amount of unidentifiable intangible assets (i.e. goodwill)
recognized. T_SALES is not significantly correlated with GOODWILL.
Of the proxies for acquisition synergy,
COMMON is negatively correlated with
GOODWILL. When the acquired company operates in similar
industries as the acquiring company, the acquisition may create relatively more
synergy through the sharing of resources such as research facilities, research
personnel and sales networks, or even better utilization of existing
technology, patents and customer base, which may enable the acquiring companies
to assign more value to identifiable intangible assets (such as technology,
patents or customer base) relative to unidentifiable intangible assets (i.e.
goodwill). The correlation between WT_CAR and GOODWILL is also negative but
insignificant.
4.1.5.
Regression Analysis
Table 5 reports the regressions results.
We first estimate the GOODWILL equations with the ordinary least square method
(OLS). Since the predictions based on our hypotheses are all one-sided, we will
apply one-sided p-values in this discussion. In the regression where only the
acquirer characteristics are included as independent variables and GOODWILL is
the dependent variable, the five acquirer/CEO characteristics ACEO_AGE,
ACEO_TENURE, A_BTM, A_VERIF, and A_SEG are all significant at 10% level or
better, and the adjusted R-square is 23%.[14]
The signs of the coefficients on ACEO_AGE, A_BTM, A_VERIF, and A_SEG are as
predicted by the hypotheses, suggesting that acquirers strategically allocate
purchase price to gain flexibility in future accounting choices.[15]
ACEO_TENURE is negatively correlated with GOODWILL, indicating that CEOs with
longer tenure allocate less to goodwill. In contrast, when TANGIBLE is the
dependent variable, none of the acquirer characteristics are significant.
Furthermore, the F-test does not reject the hypothesis that all the four
coefficients are zero, and the adjusted R-square is -5%. This is consistent
with tangible asset valuation being subject to less management discretion.
When only the target characteristics are
included as independent variables, the adjusted Rsquare is at a modest 7%
level, and T_BTM and T_RD significantly explain the variation in GOODWILL,
which is consistent with pair-wise correlations, indicating that the investment
opportunity set is more likely to be associated with unidentifiable intangible assets
(goodwill) than with identifiable tangible assets. When the same target
characteristics are applied to explaining the variation in TANGIBLE, T_BTM,
T_SALES and T_RD are all significantly different from zero, which suggests that
the investment opportunity set and production and selling efficiency are more
likely to be associated with intangible assets than with tangible assets. In
contrast, the target characteristics explain 33% of the allocation of purchase
price between tangible vs. intangible assets
(measured by TANG).
When both acquirer and target
characteristics are included in the regressions, the results remain similar.
The variables combine to explain 31% of the variation in GOODWILL and 30% of
that in TANGIBLE.
Lastly, we add the synergy measures COMMON
and WT_CAR into the regressions. The sample size is reduced to 86 because of
data restrictions. Most results remain stable except the significance level of
A_SEG is reduced, now insignificant at 10% level.
In summary, the regression results are
strongly consistent with H1, H2, and H3, and are weakly consistent with H4. As
to economic significance, the acquirer characteristics explain more of the
variation in goodwill allocation as the target company characteristics. The
results suggest that acquirers exercise discretion by allocating more of
acquisition cost to goodwill as opposed to other intangible assets when they
expect more flexibility in future goodwill impairment decisions.
4.2.
Purchase price allocation prior to SFAS 142
Our regression (1) tests H1 – H4 after
controlling for the economic determinants of the purchase price allocation
between goodwill and identifiable intangible assets. However, due to potential
measurement errors with the control variables or potential omitted correlated
variables, we cannot completely rule out an alternative interpretation: our
variables of interest affect GOODWILL because they are related to the economics
underlying the allocation. For example, acquirers with lower A_BTM (higher
Tobin’s Q) can be good firms and they can carry out better acquisitions that
generate more synergies. As a result, they record more goodwill. To mitigate
this concern, we examine the purchase price allocation prior to SFAS 142. Since
our hypotheses are based on the new accounting procedures promoted by SFAS 142,
A_BTM, A_VERIF, and A_SEG should not affect GOODWILL prior to SFAS 142.
However, if they capture the economics underlying the allocation, they would
affect GOODWILL in both the pre and the post SFAS 142 regimes.
We select a sample of acquisitions
completed between 1996 and 2000 following the procedures described in Section
4.1.1. In addition to requiring the target being public and operating in the
business service industry, we exclude all pooling of interests deals. There are
131 deals satisfying these requirements and data requirements further reduce
the sample to 73 observations with all the acquirer data and to 70 observations
with both the acquirer and the target data. The descriptive statistics of the sample
are presented in Table 6 Panel A.
We first estimate regression (1) for the
pre-SFAS 142 sample. The results are reported in the first two columns of Table
6 Panel B. The regression in column (1) only includes variables capturing
acquirer characteristics. The coefficients on ACEO_AGE, ACEO_TENURE, A_BTM,
A_VERIF, and A_SEG are all insignificant. While the coefficients on A_BTM and
A_VERIF are negative and significant in the post SFAS 142 regression, they are
positive in the pre-SFAS 142 regression, though insignificant. We then add
target characteristics variables and COMMON, a control for synergies from the
combination, in the regression in column (2). T_BTM loads marginally
significant, with the same sign as in the post SFAS 142 regression. The coefficients
on A_BTM, A_VERIF, and A_SEG are still insignificant. While the insignificant
results prevent us from making strong inferences, the pre-SFAS 142 results are
consistent with A_BTM, A_VERIF, or A_SEG reflecting new features of
SFAS 142.
Nonetheless, since some of the target
characteristics variables capturing economic determinants of the allocation
also cease to be significant in the pre-SFAS 142 regression, it is possible
that the power of the pre-SFAS 142 tests is low and reduces the significance
level of all explanatory variables. To further explore this possibility, we
estimate the following regression and its variations using all the
observations, both pre and post SFAS 142, and test the difference in
coefficients between the two regimes.
GOODWILLi
= α0 + α1 ACEO_AGEi
+ a2 ACEO_TENUREi
+ a3 A_BTMi + α4 A_VERIFi + α5
A_SEGi + a6 A_SIZEi+ α7T_BTMi
+ α8T_SALESi + α9T_ADVi + α10 T_RDi
+ α11 COMMONi + α12
Post142i + a13Post142i*ACEO_AGEi +
a14 Post142i*ACEO_TENUREi
+ a15Post142i*A_BTMi + a16Post142i*A_VERIFi
+ a17Post142i*A_SEGi + a18Post142i*A_SIZEi
+ a19Post142i*T_BTMi + a20Post142i*T_SALESi
+ a21Post142i*T_ADVi + α22Post142*T_RDi
+ α23 Post142*COMMONi + εi
(3)
Post142 is an indicator variable equaling one for post SFAS 142 observations
and zero otherwise. If our results for the pre-SFAS 142 sample are driven by a
lack of power and there is no significant difference between the pre and the
post SFAS 142 regimes, then we do not expect any of the interactive variables to
load significantly.
The results are reported in columns (3) to
(5) in Table 6 Panel B. First, acquirer characteristics variables are included
in the regression in column (3). The coefficients on
Post142*ACEO_AGE, Post142*ACEO_TENURE,
Post142*A_BTM and Post142*A_VERIF are
significant, suggesting that the determinants of GOODWILL
did change across the two periods. However, Post142*A_SEG does not load
significantly and the coefficient on A_SEG is significant. It is possible that
for multiple-segment acquirers, more business lines benefit from an acquisition
and therefore more synergies are generated and recorded as goodwill. In this
sense, A_SEG may relate to GOODWILL through its economic connection with
synergies from combinations. Column (4) adds target variables and column (5)
further adds the interactions of Post142 and target variables in the
regression. The inferences on A_BTM, A_VERIF, and A_SEG are the same as in
column (3). None of the coefficients on the interactive variables of Post142
and target characteristics are significant. The results suggest that the impact
of ACEO_AGE, A_BTM and A_VERIF on GOODWILL is unique post SFAS 142 and that
these variables likely reflect the impact of discretion in future goodwill
tests rather than economics.
Note that the pre-SFAS 142 observations
self-select themselves into the sample by choosing the purchase method and
disclosing the purchase price allocation. The allocation of the pre-SFAS 142
sample can be different from that of the post-SFAS 142 sample because of the
self-selection. However, if our variables of interest capture economics of the
allocation, it is unclear why they do not explain the allocation of disclosing
firms, potentially ‘better’ firms than non-disclosing firms. If our variables
capture opportunistic reporting incentives existing prior to SFAS 142 and the
manipulating firms chose not to disclose, we expect the disclosing and
non-disclosing firms to exhibit systematic differences in these variables.
Unreported results show that ACEO_AGE and A_BTM do not differ significantly
between the two groups. Thus, self-selection does not appear to explain all our
findings.
4.3.
Purchase price allocation post SFAS 142 and external appraisers
Independent appraisers are involved in the
valuation and allocation process in 43 out of the 103 acquisitions in our
sample. If external independent appraisers play a monitoring role in the fair
value measurement, as Dietrich et al. (2001) suggest, we expect the impact of
A_BTM, A_VERIF, and A_SEG on GOODWILL to be less pronounced when an external
appraiser is engaged for the allocation. We estimate the following regression
to test this prediction,
GOODWILLi = α0 + α1 IVi
+ α2 NON_IVi*ACEO_AGEi
+ a3NON_IVi*ACEO_TENUREi+ a4NON_IV_A_BTMi
+ α5 NON_IV*A_VERIFi + a6 NON_IV*A_SEGi
+ α7 IVi*ACEO_AGEi + a8
IVi*ACEO_TENUREi
+ a9IVi*A_BTMi + α10 IVi*A_VERIFi
+ α11 IVi*A_SEGi + α12 A_SIZEi
+ α13
T_BTMi + α14 T_SALESi
+ a15 T_ADVi + a16 T_RDi + a17
COMMONi + εi (4)
IV (NON_IV) is an indicator variable equaling one (zero) if
an acquirer engaged an external appraiser in the purchase allocation and zero
(one) otherwise. The estimation results are presented in
Table 7.
The first two columns of Table 7 report
the OLS estimation results of regression (4). The regression in column (1) only
includes acquirer characteristics variables and column (2) includes all
variables. Since the decision to engage an external appraiser is endogenous, we
also use the Heckman two-stage procedure to correct for self-selection. We
model the decision to engage an external appraiser as a function of the size of
the acquirer, the size of the target, and other target characteristics included
in regression (4). The results after controlling for self-selection are
reported in columns (3) and (4) of Table 7. Some of the coefficients on the
inverse mills ratio are significant, indicating the existence of
self-selection.
After controlling for target
characteristics and self-selection, the coefficients on
NON_IV*ACEO_AGE, NON_IV*A_BTM and NON_IV*A_VERIF are
significant as predicted by H1 – H3. The coefficients on IV*ACEO_AGE, IV*A_BTM
and IV*A_VERIF are insignificant.
Except for the higher statistical significance for the
NON_IV interactive terms than the IV interactive terms, the NON_IV interactive
terms also tend to have significantly larger magnitudes. The only exception is
IV*ACEO_TENURE. The coefficient on IV*ACEO_TENURE is significantly negative,
while that on NON_IV*ACEO_TENURE is not. The results suggest that appraisers
can reduce management reporting opportunism to a certain extent but unlikely
eliminate it.
4.4.
Segment level analysis
As an extension of H2 and H4, we expect an
acquirer with multiple reporting units to allocate more goodwill to the units
that generate more economic rents as they offer more “protection” from future
goodwill impairment. Managers obtain greater flexibility in goodwill impairment
tests when reporting units have more internally generated rents and they are
thus motivated to allocate more goodwill to these units. Conditional on the
amount of purchase price assigned to goodwill, the acquirers with multiple
segments will tend to assign more goodwill to those segments with relatively
low book-to-market ratios in order to gain flexibility in future impairment
decisions. Given the difficulty in estimating book-to-market ratios for
individual segments, we operationalize the test by using ranks of segment-level
financial performance to proxy for ranks of segment book-to-market ratio. We
argue that, within a multiple-segment company, the segments with relatively
good financial performance are likely to have relatively low book-to-market
ratio. As predicted by H4, within a multiple-segment company, a segment’s
book-to-market ratio is likely negatively correlated with the amount of
goodwill allocated to the segment; therefore, we predict that a segment’s rank
within an acquiring company based on its financial performance correlates
positively with the amount of goodwill allocated in acquisitions.
For the tests, we construct three
variables. PCT_GWi,j is the amount of goodwill allocated to segment j as a ratio of the total goodwill
assigned in the purchase price allocation of the acquisition deal i. RANKi,j is the
standardized rank of segment j among
all segments of the acquiring company in the acquisition deal i; the ranking is based on the relative
financial performance (measured as pretax income over assets, operating profit
over assets, pretax income over sales, or operating profit after depreciation
over sales, in that order, depending on the data availability in COMPUSTAT) of
all segments in the acquiring company; the ranks are standardized so that the
best performing segment receives a rank of 0.5 and the worst performing one
receives a rank of -0.5.[16]
GWW_RANKi is the goodwill-weighted rank of all segments for the
acquiring company in deal i; it is
calculated as
∑PCT _GWi, j * RANKi, j
j . If acquiring
companies allocate goodwill among their segments
independent of their relative financial performance, the
goodwill-weighted rank is going to follow a distribution with mean zero;
however, if acquiring companies systematically allocate more goodwill to their
better performing segments, the goodwill-weighted rank will have a positive
value on average. H4 predicts that: 1) the correlation between PCT_GWi,j
and RANKi,j is positive; and 2) GWW_RANK is on average positive.
To control for the commonality
between the business operations of the target company and those of different
segments of the acquiring company, we also construct two variables with
industry membership based on 4-digit SIC codes. P_MATCH is a dummy variable
assigned a value of one when a segment’s SIC code is the same as the primary
SIC code of the acquired company, and zero otherwise. R_MATCH is defined as
N1/N2, where N1 is equal to one when the segment’s SIC code is the same as any
of the multiple SIC codes assigned to the acquired company by SDC, and zero
otherwise, while N2 is the total number of different SIC codes assigned to the
acquired company by SDC. Higher values of P_MATCH and R_MATCH proxy for higher
industry commonality between a business segment of the acquiring company and
the acquired company.
Panel A of Table 8 reports the descriptive
statistics on the variables related to segment-level analysis. The sample size
is greatly reduced because not many acquirers disclose information on segments
to which they assign the goodwill, and even fewer specify amounts of goodwill
allocated to each segment. We have available information to measure PCT_GWi,j
and RANKi,j for 66 segments corresponding to 17 unique acquisition
deals. All the segment level variables show considerable variation. PCT_GW has
the lowest value of zero and the highest value of one, indicating that the
acquirers sometimes assign all goodwill to one segment and nothing to the rest;
it also has a median value of zero, indicating that more than half of the
segments have not been assigned any goodwill in the acquisitions. By
construction, RANK has a mean value of zero, a lowest value of -0.5 and a
highest value of 0.5. P_MATCH has a mean value of 0.17, indicating that in
approximately one out every six cases, a business segment of the acquiring
company has the same 4-digit SIC code as the primary industry of the target
company. Note that GWW_RANK has a mean value of 0.27, and that it is
significantly different from zero at the 1% level, consistent with our
prediction.
Panel B of Table 8 reports the
correlations. Consistent with the prediction of H4, the correlation coefficient
between PCT_GW and RANK is at 0.45, which is significant at the 1% level, but
neither of the segment-level commonality variables is significantly correlated
with the allocation of goodwill to different segments. The same pattern is
confirmed in the multiple regressions of Panel C, where only the relative
performance rank of segments helps explain the allocation of goodwill across
different segments of an acquiring company.
In summary, those acquiring companies with
multiple segments systematically assign more of the goodwill they acquire to
segments with relatively better financial performance. As a caveat, though, we
want to point out that the same results are also expected if the acquiring
companies systematically choose acquisition targets that operate in similar
industries as the ones of the acquiring companies’ relatively profitable
segments and therefore the synergy that potentially results from these
acquisitions is more likely to be related to these relatively profitable
segments. However, while one can argue that acquiring companies may want to
expand their more profitable operations, one can also argue that those
companies may want to save their relatively under-performing segments through
acquisitions. It is unclear which argument will prevail.[17]
4.5.
Robustness Checks
Our primary tests in Table 5 assume that
the likelihood of incurring economic losses in goodwill is the same across
acquirers and thereby focus on how managers’ ability to manipulate the
impairment assessment affects the allocation decision. While we do not have a
good ex ante prediction model for the likelihood of economic losses, we try to
relax the above assumption by including two variables capturing the variation
in the likelihood: stock return volatility and abnormal returns of the acquirer
at the time of announcing the acquisition.
Presumably firms with high stock price
volatility are more likely to experience temporary price declines. If goodwill
impairment is assessed based on firms’ market values, these firms are more
likely to have impairment losses. This predicts a negative correlation between
GOODWILL and acquirers’ stock return volatility. However, SFAS 142 allows
valuation methods other than the market-value-based method and firms can take
the price volatility into account in their valuation, thereby mitigating the
predicted negative correlation. Acquirers’ overpayment is also likely
positively related to the likelihood of future goodwill impairment. We use the
standard deviation of stock returns in the year prior to the acquisition to
capture acquirers’ stock return volatility and acquirer’s abnormal returns at
the time of announcing the acquisition to capture overpayment.
Our inferences from Table 5 are not affected by the inclusion
of these two variables
(untabulated). The coefficient on acquirer stock volatility
is negative but insignificant. The coefficient on acquirer abnormal returns is
positive but also insignificant. The insignificant results can be driven by our
tests lacking power. It is also possible that managers have different
expectation about the prospect of the acquisition than the market and therefore
the abnormal returns cannot capture managers’ expectation of the likelihood of
goodwill impairment.
As discussed in Section 3, the variables
capturing the benefits of manipulation or litigation risks, i.e., A_SP, A_NW,
A_LITI, and A_AUDIT, do not exhibit much variation in our sample. Not
surprisingly, they do not load significantly in the GOODWILL regression. The
coefficients on A_SP and A_NW are positive and that on A_LITI is negative,
consistent with predictions. Their inclusion does not affect inferences on
other variables. We also examine whether there are other debt covenant ratios
affecting the allocation decision. There are 32 firms with covenants or
performance pricing schemes based on earnings, but all of them define earnings
as EBITDA. The differential treatment of goodwill and other intangibles does
not make a difference for EBITDA-based debt contracts.
We recognize that governance mechanisms
potentially constrain management accounting choices. Specifically in our
setting, they could affect an acquirer’s allocation of the purchase price.
Existing research suggests that institutional investors are more actively
involved in monitoring (Ashbaugh et al., 2003). We obtained institutional
holdings data from Spectrum. The
percentage of institutional holdings also does not significantly affect GOODWILL or TANG.
We further conduct the following tests to
check the robustness of our results. First, since GOODWILL, the dependent
variable in regressions (1), (3), and (4), is a proportion, the OLS regressions
in Tables 5, 6, and 7 might be misspecified. We use two alternative methods to
estimate the regressions. 1) We normalize GOODWILL by subtracting the mean of
GOODWILL from each value and then deflating it by the standard deviation of
GOODWILL. All the inferences remain intact when we use the normalized GOODWILL
as the dependent variable. 2) We apply a logistic transformation of GOODWILL
using the following formula: NEW_GOODWILL = log
(GOODWILL/(1 – GOODWILL)). In applying this formula, when
GOODWILL equals one, we replace it by 0.9999. When GOODWILL equals zero, we
replace it by 0.0001. Note that this transformation at zero and one is
arbitrary and it can be particularly problematic in our setting given that it not
rare for GOODWILL to take these values. After the transformation, NEW_GOODWILL
is no longer bounded. The inferences in Tables 5 and 7 are unaffected by the
transformation. However, the differences in the coefficients on A_BTM and
A_VERIF between the pre and post SFAS 142 regimes become insignificant.
Second, in order to ensure that our
results are not driven by outliers, we winsorize the variables at the top and
bottom 2.5% and re-run the regressions. We obtain qualitatively similar results
after the winsorization.
Third, we examine the sensitivity of our
results to alternative definitions of variables. We measure the book-to-market
ratios alternatively by the book value of equity plus total liabilities over
the market value of equity plus the book value of liabilities. We also define
the verifiability of acquirer assets as the sum of cash and investments divided
by total assets. We replace A_SEG with the logarithm of the number of
segments. Finally, we set COMMON equal
to one if the value is above the sample median and zero otherwise. Our main
results are robust to these alternative variable definitions.
Fourth, we include additional controls for
target characteristics, such as target size and performance measured by ROA.
These variables do not load significantly in the regressions and their
inclusion does not affect our other inferences.
5.
Conclusion
This study investigates whether and to
what extent management’s reporting opportunism rather than the underlying
economics affects the valuation of acquired goodwill and identifiable
intangibles. Specifically, we examine the factors affecting firms’ allocation
of purchase price to goodwill and identifiable intangible assets upon the
completion of a merger or an acquisition. We conduct the tests on acquisitions
with targets operating primarily in the business services industry. By focusing
on a single industry with relatively homogeneous asset structure, we can better
capture the economic determinants of the allocation decision. The economic
significance of intangibles in this industry further increases the power of the
tests.
SFAS 142 affords management greater
flexibility in the accounting for goodwill than that for most identifiable
intangibles, since goodwill is assessed for impairment based on unverifiable
fair value estimates while identifiable intangible assets, except those with an
indefinite life, are still amortized. We expect that managers allocate more
purchase price to goodwill relative to amortizable intangibles to reduce
amortization expenses, when they are able to avoid reporting impairment
writeoffs in the future or when they benefit more from reducing amortization
expenses.
We find that post SFAS 142, acquirers with
the three characteristics identified by Ramanna (2006), namely a high market-to-book
ratio, unverifiable assets, and multiple reporting units, allocate more
purchase price to goodwill. While the relation between the existence of
multiple segments and the goodwill-intangible ratio is sensitive to the
inclusion of different controls for the underlying economics, the association
between the market-to-book ratio (the verifiability of assets) and the
allocation ratio is robust to alternative specifications. We also find that
older CEOs who likely benefit more from reducing intangible amortization and
boosting up short-term earnings allocate more purchase price to goodwill.
We also find that the incremental
explanatory power of acquirer/CEO characteristics is greater than the variables
capturing the underlying economics of the allocation. This finding suggests
that management accounting preferences have a substantial impact on the
reliability of financial reporting when accounting measures lack verifiability.
In contrast, we do not find a significant association between acquirer characteristics
and the allocation of purchase price to tangible assets, the valuation of which
presumably involves less subjectivity.
Furthermore, we examine the purchase price
allocation of acquisitions prior to SFAS 142 in order to further mitigate the
concern that our variables capturing management’s expected discretion in future
goodwill tests are related to the economics underlying the allocation. We do
not find acquirers’ CEO age, market-to-book ratio, and verifiability of assets,
constructed based management incentives arguable granted by under SFAS 142,
explain the pre-SFAS 142 allocation. Also, in the regression to explain the
allocation decision, the coefficients on these variables differ significantly
between the pre and post SFAS 142 regimes. Our findings suggest our post SFAS
142 results cannot be solely explained by the economics underlying the
goodwill/intangible valuation.
In addition, we investigate mechanisms
that potentially enhance the reliability of the valuation of intangible assets.
We find that external appraisers can constrain management’s reporting
opportunism to a certain extent but unlikely eliminate it.
Finally, for a sub-sample of multi-segment
acquirers, we find that more goodwill is allocated to the more profitable
reporting units, consistent with management intending to obtain greater
flexibility in future goodwill assessment and/or avoid reporting impairment.
While we cannot rule out the possibility that the results are driven by firms
expanding their profitable product lines through acquisitions, the relationship
is robust to controls for synergies between the acquiring companies and the
acquired companies.
This study makes several contributions to
the literature. First, our findings help evaluate the consequences of SFAS 142
and the reliability of intangible valuation. Our finding that management
opportunistic reporting incentives are more important than the economic
determinants of the initial valuation of acquired intangibles casts doubt on
the reliability of intangible valuation under SFAS 142. The evidence suggests
that the impact of management discretion cannot be overlooked in assessing
intangible valuation. Second, our findings have implications for
fair-value-based accounting procedures that are built on unverifiable estimates
in general. SFAS 142 is considered an important step towards fair-value-based
accounting (Watts, 2003). Our findings suggest that the unverifiable fair value
estimates can be biased as a result of management taking advantage of the
discretion in measurement. Third, we find that external appraiser may help
improve the reliability of fair value measurements. Finally, in response to Healy
and Wahlen’s (1999) call for more research on the manipulation of specific
accruals, this study also contributes to the earnings management literature by
documenting the manipulation of a specific accounting procedure that has not
yet been explored.
We analyze one of the accounting choices
under SFAS 142. The analysis can be extended to other choices that involve
unverifiable estimation. Particularly, it would be a natural extension to
examine how management’s flexibility in the goodwill impairment tests affects
their decision to report an impairment loss subsequent to the acquisition.
References
Andrade, G., M. Mitchell, and E. Stafford,
2001, New Evidence and Perspectives on Mergers, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15, 103-120.
Ashbaugh, Hollis, Ryan LaFond, and Brian
Mayhew. 2003. Do Non-Audit Services Compromise Auditor Independence? Further
Evidence. The Accounting Review, 78:
611- 639.
Barth, M.E., M.B. Clement, G. Foster, and
R. Kasznik, 1998. Brand Values and Capital Market Valuation. Review of Accounting Studies, 3, 41-68.
Beatty, A, and J. Weber, 2006. Accounting
Discretion in Fair Value Estimates: An Examination of SFAS 142 Goodwill
Impairments. Journal of Accounting
Research, 44, No. 2, 257-288.
Bens, D.A., and W. Hetzler, 2006. The
Information Content and Timeliness of Fair Value Asset Impairment
Triggers: Goodwill Write-offs Before,
During and After Implementation of SFAS 142.
Working paper, University of Arizona.
Dechow, P.M., and R.G. Sloan, 1991.
Executive incentives and the horizon problem: An empirical investigation. Journal of Accounting and Economics 14,
51-89.
Dietrich, R., M.S. Harris, and K.A.
Muller, 2001. The reliability of investment property fair value estimates. Journal of Accounting and Economics 30,
125-158.
Financial Accounting Standards Board,
1995. Statement of Financial Accounting Standards No. 121:
Accounting
for the impairment of long-lived assets and for long-lived assets to be
disposed of. Norwalk, CT.
Financial Accounting Standards Board,
2001. Statement of Financial Accounting Standards No. 142:
Goodwill
and Other Intangible Assets. Norwalk, CT.
Francis, J., D. Philbrick, and K.
Schipper, 1994. Shareholder litigation and corporate decisions.
Journal
of Accounting Research 32, 137-164.
Healy, P., 1985. The effect of bonus
schemes on accounting decisions. Journal
of Accounting and Economics 7, 85-107.
Healy, P, and J. Wahlen, 1999. A review of
the earnings management literature and its implications for standard setting. Accounting Horizons 13, 365-383.
Holthausen, R.H., and R.L. Watts, 2001.
The Relevance of the Value-relevance Literature for Financial Accounting
Standard Setting. Journal of Accounting
and Economics, 31, 3-75.
Li, Z., Shroff, P. K. and Venkataraman,
R., 2006. Goodwill Impairment Loss: Causes and Consequences. Working paper,
University of Minnesota.
Lys, T., and L. Vincent, 1995. An analysis
of value destruction in AT&T’s acquisition of NCR.
Journal
of Financial Economics 39, 352-378.
Johnson, J.D., 1993. Goodwill – An Eternal
Controversy. The CPA Journal, April
1993.
Moehrle, S.R., and J.A., Moehrle, 2001.
Say Goodbye to Pooling and Goodwill Amortization.
Journal
of Accountancy, 192, 31-38.
Muller, K.A., 1999. An Examination of the Voluntary
Recognition of Acquired Brand Names in the United Kingdom. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 26, 179-191.
Muller, K.A., and E.J. Riedl, 2002.
External monitoring of property appraisal estimates and information asymmetry. Journal of Accounting Research 40,
865-881.
Pender, K., 2001. Large goodwill
write-downs a sign company made bad buyouts. The San Francisco Chronicle, August 2, 2001.
Ramanna, K., 2006. The Implication of
Fair-value Accounting: Evidence from the Political Economy of Goodwill
Accounting. Working paper, MIT.
Smith, C.W. and R.L. Watts, 1992. The
Investment Opportunity and Corporate Financing, Dividend, and Compensation
Policies, Journal of Financial Economics,
32, 263-292.
Watts, R.L., 2003. Conservatism in
Accounting Part I: Explanations and Implications. Accounting Horizons, 17, 207-222.
Watts, R.L., 1993. A Proposal for Research
on Conservatism. Working paper, University of Rochester.
Wyatt, A., 2005. Accounting Recognition of
Intangible Assets: Theory and Evidence on Economic Determinants. The Accounting Review, 80, 967-1003.
[1] We thank Hemang Desai,
Mary Barth, Rebecca Hann, Clive Lennox, Ross Watts, Jerry Zimmerman, and
seminar participants at the AAA 2007 Financial Accounting and Reporting Section
(FARS) meeting, the University of Minnesota Mini Conference on Empirical Research,
HKUST, and the University of Southern California for their helpful comments and
suggestions. We also thank Fang Wan and Junqi Zou for their excellent research
assistance. All errors are our own.
[2] A reporting unit is an
operating segment as defined in SFAS 131, Disclosures
about Segments of an Enterprise and Related Information, or one level below
an operating segment.
[3] We recognize that under
certain circumstances, such as corporate restructuring or management turnovers,
managers can include goodwill write-offs as a part of earnings baths. The
possibility of hiding goodwill impairment in earnings baths may make goodwill
write-offs appear less costly to managers than otherwise. However, anecdotal
evidence (e.g., the AOL Time Warner goodwill write-off in 2002) suggests that
when impairment occurs, managers are not always able to avoid losses in human
capital by taking a ‘bath’.
[4] While intangibles are not
always recognized in accounting, tangibles, purchased or internally
constructed, are all recorded as assets. Barth et al. (1998) and Wyatt (2005)
note that reliability is a major reason why intangibles are not always
recorded. These arguments imply that measurement of tangible assets generally
involves less discretion and is more reliable.
[5] See Para. 7, SFAS 144, Accounting for the Impairment or Disposal of
Long-lived Assets.
[6] An example is AOL Time
Warner. Shortly after AOL Time Warner announced a massive goodwill impairment
write-off of $54 billion related to the merger with Time Warner in March 2002,
its interim chief stepped down and the company as well as several top
executives was sued for issuing misleading statements.
[7] Arguably, when managers
expect greater flexibility in future goodwill impairment tests, they may also
have incentives to lower valuation of tangible assets and therefore increase
the amount of purchase price assigned to goodwill. However, tangible asset
values are likely more verifiable and less manipulable. Our tests in Section
4.2 show that managers’ discretion in tangible assets valuation is a less
important issue in our setting.
[8] For example, for the
publishing industry, publication rights and licensing agreements are
significant intangible assets unique to the industry. For pharmaceutical
companies, patents on drugs are significant intangibles. 8 For a
small portion of our sample, where the information is not available from the
10-K filings, we also search through relevant 10-Q filings and annual or
quarterly reports for the information.
[9] In some cases, the
financial data of the target is unavailable for the year prior to the
acquisition year and we then use the financial information two years before the
acquisition. This happens mostly when the acquisition occurs at the beginning
of the year, before the annual report of the prior year is issued.
[10]
In most cases, the identifiable intangible assets with an indefinite life are
trademarks, though not all trademarks are considered to have an indefinite
life. Only in two cases, other identifiable intangibles are considered to have
an indefinite life (developed technology in one case and in the other,
agreement).
[11]
We use the number of operating segments to proxy the number of reporting units because
firms do not always disclose information on reporting units. However, reporting
units can be one level below reporting segments. Noise in this proxy can reduce
the power of our tests.
[12] All inferences in
subsequent regression tests are not sensitive to replacing A_SEG with
A_SEG*Size, which was used by Ramanna (2006) to capture the discretion in
goodwill impairment tests.
[13] In untabulated analysis,
we find no significant correlation between the acquirer’s abnormal announcement
period stock return, which may proxy for overpayment by the acquirer, and
purchase price allocation.
[14] Note A_SIZE is only
marginally significant here and therefore does not contribute much to the
explanatory power of the model. Even if A_SIZE is removed from the regression,
the adjusted R-square remains at 22%.
[15] We also estimate this
regression for the sample with data available to compute the target
characteristic variables.
The coefficient estimates
and R2 are very similar to those reported in Table 5.
[16] While different companies
may use different definitions in reporting segment level financial performance,
each firm should apply the same definition to all its business segments.
[17]
A more powerful test could be to compare the segment allocation of tangible
assets or identifiable intangible assets to that of the goodwill. However, we
are not able to find disclosure about the segment allocation of any assets
other than goodwill.
Post Comment
No comments